Welcome!

Welcome to the NAIP's English-language blog on IP-related news and topics for inventors, engineers, companies and patent professionals in Asia. As we get started, feel free to share your thoughts, comments or any suggestions, and check back often for the latest updates.

Bookmark this page! or Subscribe (RSS)

Trademarking Signs with "China" or "National" in China

by Werner Chiu, NAIP Patent Research
Photo by rvw
This article focuses specifically on trademarking in China when the sign in the trademark application includes the words "China" or "National" or if it is similar to existing government-related designs or objects.

On August 19, 2010 China's State Administration for Industry & Commerce issued the "Examination Standards for Trademarks Containing "China" and "National" as the First Word" specifically referencing provisions 1, 2, 3, 7, 8 of Article 10 and provision 1 and 3 of Article 11 of China's Trademark Law. The Articles are listed below (in blue) and include a more detailed explanation or interpretation of the listed provisions.

Article 10 of China Trademark law states that the following signs shall not be used as trademarks:

(1) those identical with or similar to the State name, national flag, national emblem, military flag, or decorations, of the People's Republic of China, with names of the places where the Central and State organs are located, or with the names and designs of landmark buildings;

Explanation:
A sign that bears any similarity to the State name, even in abbreviated or contracted form, both in English (such as CN, CHN, P.R.C., China or PR of China, etc...) or Chinese, will be rejected. The same applies to signs with similarities to China's national flag (red with five yellow stars); emblem (circular in shape, with grain-borders and featuring Tiananmen gate under the five stars); military flag, (the flag of the People's Liberation Army consisting of a single yellow star and the Chinese characters for "8" and "1" on a red background); and "decorations", which refers to any medals or decorations awarded by China's government to individuals or organizations who have contributed to the State or society. Finally, similarities to places with Central and State organs or landmark buildings, including Tiananmen Square, Xinhua Gate, the Great Hall and so on, is prohibited.

(2) those identical with or similar to the State names, national flags, national emblems or military flags of foreign countries, except that the foreign state government agrees otherwise on the use;

Explanation:
Using the name of any country, in Chinese, English or the original language, in a trademark, such as "France Bags", is prohibited. Agreement on use from the foreign government must be in written form. A successful trademark application in its "native" country is considered agreement/approval from the government.

(3) those identical with or similar to the names, flags or emblems or names, of international intergovernmentaI organizations, except that the organizations agree otherwise on the use or that it is not easy for the use to mislead the public;

Explanation:
Examples include the United Nations, European Union, World Trade Organization and so on, inclusive of full names, as well as abbreviated or contracted forms.

(4) those identical with or similar to official signs and hallmarks, showing official control or warranty by them, except that the use thereof is otherwise authorized;

(5) those identical with or similar to the symbols, or names, of the Red Cross or the Red Crescent;

(6) those having the nature of discrimination against any nationality;

(7) those having the nature of exaggeration and fraud in advertising goods;

Explanation:
Any sign that overly-expresses the characteristics or the quality of the goods or services, and easily causes the public to misinterpret the characteristics or quality of the goods or services is prohibited. For example, trademarks such as "National Liquor" white wine or "Ultimate" mineral water, etc., are not allowed.

(8) those detrimental to socialist morals or customs, or having other unhealthy influences.

Explanation:
"Socialist Morals" refers to the generally accepted standard behavior and norms of the Chinese people, as well as the positive customs and habits in a certain period of time. "Unhealthy influences" are when the text, graphics or other elements of the trademark adversely affect China's political, economic, cultural, religious, ethnic and other social and public interests and public order.

The geographical names as the administrative divisions at or above the county level and the foreign geographical names well known to the public shall not be used as trademarks, but such geographical terms as have otherwise meanings or are a part of collective marks/or a certification marks shall be exclusive. Where a trademark using any of the above-mentioned geographical names has been approved and registered, it shall continue to be valid.

Furthermore, Article 11 states that the following signs shall not be registered as trademarks:

(1) those only comprising generic names, designs or models of the goods in respect of which the trademarks are used;

Explanation:
This refers to signs that are similar to China' standards, industry standards, or conventional names, graphics or shapes. Full names, acronyms, abbreviations and common nicknames are included. Examples include as China's "502 glue", "Korea White Ginseng", and "S" clothing.

(2) those having direct reference to the quality, main raw materials, function, use, weight, quantity or other features of the goods in respect of which the trademarks are used; and

(3) those lacking distinctive features.

The signs under the preceding paragraphs may be registered as trademarks where they have acquired the distinctive features through use and become readily identifiable.

Explanation:
Simple lines, common geometric shapes, or unembellished combinations of letters (for example, "C" Clothing).

In addition to pointing out the provisions, the Standards further clarified the reasoning behind examinations:

1. Trademark applications comprised of, or containing the terms "'National' + name of good" will be rejected due to "constituting exaggeration and fraud", "lack of distinctive features" and/or "having adverse impact".

2. Trademark applications with "National" as the first word, but without the "'National' + name of good" combination, will be treated differently and rejected due to its harm to fair competitiveness, fraud or negative political influence.

So if a trademark application with "China" or "National" in the sign does not contradict any of the above provisions, can it be trademarked? Not quite yet. The applicant must also satisfy the following conditions:

  • The applicant's qualifications must be approved by the State Council or a competent authority. The applicant's (company) name must be the same as the name on the trademark registration information.
  • The trademark must be identical to the applicant's (company) name or its abbreviated version, which must have also been approved by the State Council or a competent authority.
  • The trademark and the applicant must have close corresponding relationship.
  • The scope of the goods or services referred to by the applied trademark must be consistent with the approved business scope of the applicant (his/her business).

Although China's Trademark Law contains hints of socialism, the Law itself shows development on par with those of other countries. After all, the purpose of trademarks is to prevent confusion between domestic or international names, or create false, exaggerated assumptions. These are the basic tenets of trademarks that every country must have.


Read more...

TIPO to Reduce Design Patent Annuities

by Anita Li, NAIP Editorial

On 1 July 2011, new patent annuities for Taiwan design patents will go into effect. The draft of the new fee structure was presented at a public hearing on 22 March in order to collect general opinions and feedback before submission to the Taiwan Executive Yuan to finalize the draft.

Goal: Increase Design Patent Applications
At the public hearing, Director General of TIPO Wang Mei-hua stated that, although the number of invention patent applications has steadily increased in recent years, the number of design patent applications has actually been gradually decreasing. Director Wang also put forth the question that, although the patent annuities for design patent were already significantly reduced on 1 January 1, 2010, is there still room for further reduction? Director Wang indicated that considering the high percentage of small to medium size businesses (SMB) that account for Taiwan’s industrial make-up, the stagnant growth in design patent applications may suggest that design patent fees may still be too high.

In order to facilitate the government’s goal in supporting the development of Taiwan’s cultural and creative industry, TIPO hopes to increase the number of design patent applications by adjusting design patent annuities. TIPO believes a reduction in design patent annuities may offer practical assistance to natural persons and small enterprises that are comparatively weak financially. Lower overall costs would help better the environment for SMB in Taiwan.

Furthermore, TIPO also pointed out that feedback from industry representatives, who said considering Taiwan’s economic scale, the overall costs of a Taiwan design patent is rather high in comparison with those of other countries. Therefore, TIPO conducted research into the total design patent costs in European countries, the US, Japan, Korea, China and Australia, when drafting the proposal.

Based on this research, TIPO proposed the following fee reductions:
Design patent annuities: NT$ 1,000 per year from the first to the third year; NT$ 2,000 per year from the fourth to sixth year, and NT$ 3,000 from the seventh year onward. Under the new fee structure, over a period of 10 years the total amount of patent annuities would be NT$ 21,000. If including the NT$ 3,000 application fee and NT$ 1,000 issue fee, the total charge is NT$ 25,000. In comparison with the existing fee schedule, total costs have been reduced by around 40.5%, or NT$ 17,000

Furthermore, under the new fee structure, applicants who are schools, natural persons or SMBs will receive additional patent annuities discounts from the first to sixth years. During the first to third year, they need only pay NT$ 200 patent annuities per year, a reduction of NT$ 800. During the fourth to sixth years, the fee will be reduced by NT$1,200 to only NT$ 800 per year. Over then 10 year lifetime of a design patent, total official fee costs, including the patent annuities, application fee and issue fee, would be NT$ 19,000. In comparison to the existing fee schedule, the reduction is around 54.8%, or NT$ 23,000.

TIPO Design Patent Fee Structure


Existing Patent Fees

New, Proposed Fees

Fees for Qualified Schools, Natural Persons, SMBs

1st ~ 3rd Year

2,500

1,000

200

4th ~ 6th Year

3,500

2,000

800

7th Year Onward

5,000

3,000

3,000

Total Patent Annuities

38,000

21,000

15,000

Application Fee & Issue Fee

4,000

4,000

4,000

Total

42,000

25,000

19,000

Fee Reduction

/

17,000

23,000

Reduction Rate

/

40.5%

54.8%

Source: TIPO Public Hearing
Note: Effective on 1 July 2011
Units: NTD


Read more...

Patent firm North America Intellectual Property (NAIP) has received notice from the Taiwan Intellectual Property Office (TIPO) for issue of its 10,000th patent granted. Patent number M398638, for a display device, was filed on behalf of client Chunghwa Picture Tubes and published on February 21st, 2011.

"10,000 patents granted is truly impressive," says NAIP Patent Engineer Manager and Taiwan Patent Attorney Frank Wu. “Unlike other Taiwan firms that mainly translate existing foreign patent applications or focus on design and utility model patents, over 75% of our work is in the complete drafting, filing and prosecuting of high tech invention patents. We are really helping Taiwan companies turn their ideas into patents.”

As of March 21st, TIPO's online patent search system shows 10,064 patents granted with NAIP as the patent agent firm of record. Of this number, 9,539 are invention, 450 are utility model, and 75 design patents.

"Last year, NAIP reached over 10,000 United States patent applications filed, making us the largest US patent filing firm in Taiwan by volume," NAIP Patent Engineering Management Supervisor Almon Chen. "This 10,000 Taiwan patent grants milestone just proves again the depth of our experience and expertise in high tech patents."

With clients including 9 of the 10 Taiwan companies listed in BusinessWeek's Infotech 100, NAIP is renowned in the Taiwan IP industry as a high tech patent specialist with focus on Circuits, Telecommunication, Software, Image Processing, Semiconductor Materials, Memory Manufacturing, Measurement, Opto-electronics, Solar Energy, Chemical Engineering, Mechanical Structures and Data Storage Devices.

Read more...

Taiwan Patent Office Fees

by Jeffrey Chang, NAIP Editorial

When devising IP strategy, for all the consideration given to markets, competitors, suppliers and so on, one thing always seems to be the deciding factor: cost. Although most economies are already two years removed from the global economic crisis, corporate budgets have yet to fully recover, and IP managers need details to shape strategy effectively. And as Taiwan continues to gain greater importance for high tech industries, the costs are no small investment. To understand patent costs, let's take a look at Taiwan Patent Offices Fees, the latest of which came into effect on January 1, 2010


The absolute bare costs for Taiwan patents from application to grant and the first 3 years maintenance fees are:


    Invention Patent - NT$19,000 (approximately US$ 633*)

    Utility Model Patent - NT$ 11,500 (US$383)

    Design Patent - NT$ 11,500 (US$383).


*based on an exchange rate of US$1.00 to NT$ 30.00


Don't jump for joy yet—these costs do not include fees for amendments, divisionals, appeals and other options. Most significantly, they do not include agent/attorney fees, which make up the lion's share of any patent cost. But since these services vary widely in both price and quality, we will not cover them here.


Patent Office Fees – A Detailed Look

(All Fees in New Taiwan Dollars)

Invention Patent Fees

Filing

3,500

 

Request for Early Publication

1,000

Substantive Examination

7,000

requested within 3 years of filing

+ 800/claim in excess of 10

+ 500/page in excess of 50

Re-examination

8,000

+ 500/page in excess of 50

Request for division

3,500

 

Request for correction of specification or drawings

2,000

 

Request for other change(s)

300

for two or more changes: 300

Issue

1,000

 

Annuity

2,500

per year (1st-3rd)

5,000

per year (4th-6th)

8,000

per year (7th -9th)

16,000

per year (10th & beyond)

Request for invalidation

10,000

 

Request for extension of patent term

9,000

Request for compulsory license of a patent

100,000

Request to revoke compulsory license of a patent

100,000

Filing a supplemental brief, reasons for correction or evidence in an invalidation

2,000

Request for conversion of an application into an invention patent application

3,500


Aside from requisite base costs (in blue), other commonly incurred fees are excess claim or page fees, which were only instituted in January 2010, and the re-examination fee—essentially an additional stage for examination of an application.


Note that no additional fees are required for accelerated examination, claiming priority rights, delaying publication, or even extensions of term for replies to office communications. Furthermore, no official fees are incurred for filing appeals. Compare this to the USPTO, where filing a notice of appeal incurs a US$ 540 Office Fee.


Furthermore, in certain situations TIPO will refund the Substantive Examination or Re-examination fee. If the applicant withdraws his application before the first examiner opinion is issued, the applicant may apply for a refund of the substantive examination fee, including excess claims and excess pages fees, or the reexamination fee, including excess pages fees.


If an English translation of the first page and abstract of the specification is submitted with the application, an NT$ 800 discount is applied to the filing or conversion fee.


Utility Model Patent Fees

Filing

3,000

 

Filing a divisional application

3,000

Applying for correction of specification or drawings

2,000

Request for other change(s)

300

for two or more changes: 300

Issue

1,000

 

Application for a Technical Report

5,000

Annuity

2,500

per year (1st-3rd)

4,000

per year (4th-6th)

8,000

per year (7th & beyond)

Filing an application of invalidation

9,000

 

Filing a supplemental brief or evidence in an invalidation

2,000

Request for conversion of an application into a utility model patent application

3,000


Aside from required costs, the most common fee is the application for a Technical Report. The Technical Report is a valuable tool for exercising the rights of a Utility Model Patent and is highly recommended, as it may absolve the patentee of damages claims should the Utility Model Patent ultimately be proven invalid. If the Utility Model Patent is revoked or abandoned before the report is complete, production of the technical report will be cancelled and the fee refunded.


If a utility model application is converted to an invention application, and an English translation of the first page of the specifications and abstract are provided, the conversion fee is reduced by 800 NTD.


Design Patent Fees

Filing

3,000

 

Filing an associated design patent

3,000

Filing a divisional application

3,000

Re-examination

3,500

Applying for correction of specification or drawings

2,000

Request for other change(s)

300

for two or more changes: 300

Issue

1,000

 

Annuity

2,500

per year (1st-3rd)

3,500

per year (4th-6th)

5,000

per year (7th & beyond)

Filing a supplemental brief or evidence in an invalidation

2,000

 

Filing an application of invalidation

8,000

Request for conversion of an application into a design patent application

3,000



In comparison, design patent costs are simpler. One particular option of note is conversion of an application into a design patent application, which may be useful if the fast-moving market necessitates strategic changes. If the conversion is made in time, fees from substantive examination of invention application, or technical report may be refunded as well.

Annuities

Another point of note is payment of annuities. At the USPTO, annuities (maintenance fees) must be paid in 3-year blocks. At TIPO, patents are renewed per year, although pre-payment is possible to reduce hassle and risk! And if fees are adjusted during this time period, fees must be re-paid (if higher) or they are refunded (if lower). If annuities are not paid on time, a surcharge of 100% is incurred and the fee must be submitted before 6 months from expiration of the deadline.


Furthermore, annuities can be reduced under certain conditions:

  1. A patentee who is a natural person, foreign school, domestic or foreign small and medium enterprise may apply for fee reduction in the amount of NT$800 deducted per year for the 1st - 3rd year; and NT$1,200 deducted per year for the 4th - 6th year.

  2. A patentee who is a natural person with no capital for annuity payment may apply on a yearly basis to the Patent Authority for annuity exemption.


Other Official Fees

Recordal of assignment or inheritance for the right to apply for patent

2,000

Recordal of assignment or inheritance for the patent right

2,000

Recordal of license of patent right

2,000

Recordal of pledge over patent right

2,000

Recordal of extinguishment of pledge over patent right

2,000

Recordal of other changes pertaining to pledge over patent right

300

Recordal of trust of patent right

2,000

Recordal of obliteration of patent trust

2,000

Recordal of ownership of patent trust

2,000

Recordal of other changes pertaining to patent trust

300

Applying for a certified copy of a document

1,000

Request for an interview

1,000

Request for an inspection of the experiments, models or specimens conducted/submitted

5,000


Conclusion

Finally, one particularly important area that patent applicants must understand is TIPO's "attitude" toward deadlines and application requirements. In many patent offices, like the USPTO or EPO, in many situations where an application has "died" due to missing documents, late responses or unsubmitted fees, the application may be revived—upon payment of a hefty surcharge. In TIPO, the procedure is slightly different:

  1. When a person filing a patent application or going through any other procedures in connection with patent matters has delayed beyond any statutory or given time limit, or has defaulted in payment of any fees prior to the deadline fixed therefor, the application filed or the other procedures instituted by him/her shall be dismissed, unless his/her delay to act within the given time limit or his/her failure in payment by the deadline has been corrected before an administrative decision is rendered by the Patent Authority.

Essentially, if you fail to submit monies or documents in time, you are able to correct the mistake--but only if you are faster than TIPO. No surcharges required. TIPO does notify applicants of missing documents or late payments for SOME options, but ultimately proper submission of many fees and requirements is entirely the responsibility of the applicant. That is why an experienced and reliable patent partner is critical to the success of an application.


LINKS:

TIPO Regulations of Patent Fees
http://www.tipo.gov.tw/en/MultiMedia_FileDownload.ashx?guid=7cccfc3a-3953-4b1d-9435-6838cdd5951e


Read more...

By Bravo Li, NAIP Editorial

As rational members of a capitalist society, we are, for the most part, trained to see monopolies as bad for the market. Monopolies create artificially high prices. They stifle competition. They steal candy from children and other evil acts. We also know, as IP industry professionals, that patents are essentially monopolies granted by the government. Therefore, through specious reasoning, patents are evil. Right?


Well, that depends on who you ask. Here, we will take a quick, simplified look at this question from an economist's perspective to answer this question, hopefully once and for all.

A Economist's Definition of Patents: Monopolies Granted & Enforced by a Government

In economics, a government-granted monopoly is also called a de jure monopoly, which is a coercive monopoly. Potential competitors are excluded from the market owing to regulations or other governmental mechanism of enforcement. This coercive power comes from an exclusive privilege granted by a government to a private individual or firm to be the only provider of a good or service. Patents are examples of government-granted monopolies; so are copyright and trademarks.

How Does a Monopolist Maximize Profit?

To understand how a monopolist maximizes its profits (and acts all evil in the process), first we must understand a fundamental tenet of economics: The lower the price of a normal good, the higher the overall demand for that good. This states an inverse relationship between price and demand and a downward-sloping demand curve.

Furthermore, suppliers of a product produce more as the price goes up, and less if the price goes down. This means an upward sloping supply curve. The intersection of these two curves is the market price.

In a market where supply is controlled by a monopolist, however, the supply curve is comparatively steeper—meaning the price at which a product is sold in the market is higher, but the quantity sold is lower.

The monopolist does this simply because it wishes to maximize its profits. For those interested in a brief discussion of that math and economics involved, please see the addendum.





Monopolies Are Evil – The Evidence

Monopolies are considered evil because they cause a net loss to a society's welfare or wealth, which is called "dead weight loss"(see graph 2).

Graph 2


Deadweight loss is the inefficiency caused by, for example, monopoly pricing. By causing a difference between the pre-monopoly price received by a monopoly firm and the post-monopoly price paid by consumers, the monopoly firm secures a profit, or "surplus", represented by the pink area labeled monopoly revenue. This revenue comes at the expense of the consumer surplus (in yellow) and producer surplus (in blue) that would have existed in the free market equilibrium. The blue "gone" triangle of deadweight loss goes to no one because the monopoly pricing has prevented those transactions. This loss represents the inefficiency and vice of patent monopolies claimed by anti-patent advocates.

But… Not All Monopolies Are Not Evil

In economics, a more benign denotation for "dead weight loss" exists: Rent.

Whereas the term "dead weight loss" suggests that monopoly pricing results in overall waste, the term "rent" suggests that society is somehow subsidizing the monopoly's existence. These terms have undoubtedly caused much contention in economic studies. But which one is more accurate for a patent monopoly?

The following is the profit maximization formula for a monopolist:


TR(Q) is the monopolist's total revenue and TC(Q) is the total cost. π(Q) represents the profit level of a monopoly producer when the production quantity reaches Q.

If for any reason the profit function π(Q) is (or is predicted to be) 0, the production quantity Q of a monopoly will be zero. No rationale producer would be willing to continue any production activity without profit. And as strange as it seems, some situations do exist in which without any government subsidies or "rents", producers would not produce anything—even if buyers do exist.

Imagine a subway system. Would any business be willing to build an extensive system that, once completed, could be utilized by any other company without fees? Furthermore, would any company build that subway system if the population of that city were only 1000 people? The issue is in fixed costs and market uncertainty—two areas for which patents and their potential are notoriously unreliable.

Patents Are Monopolies that Need Special Care

Each year, inventors and organizations spend billions of dollars to develop and file their inventions as patents. Each year, some of these inventions go on to revolutionize (or create) markets, even changing the way societies run. But only some. The rest of these ideas, even if they become patents, sit stacked and unused, representing billion of dollars wasted and countless producers run out of business. The reasons why ideas and patents go unused vary, but regardless of the exact reason, the result is simple: despite a potential market existing and potential gain available for capture, the producer sees no potential for profit and therefore does not produce.

Fortunately, the potential of ideas are so strong, governments have implemented policies, subsidies and many more methods to encourage their continual generation and commercialization. Patents are simply one of these methods. And, therefore, in this light, we can see that some monopolies, such as patents, do require these "rents". The utility, innovation, and novelty offered by a successful patent can potentially bring huge benefit to society. And these benefits justify paying "rent" to a patent owner for its monopolistic existence.

So are patent monopolies evil? With this basic understanding of economics and the nature of market monopolies, we can easily see that "evil patent monopoly" is an overstatement.

Conclusion

Patents do demonstrate some characteristics of a monopoly, specifically: exclusive ownership as a sole provider of a technology through legal privilege and command of supply. The key point, however, is that a patent, which is a government-granted monopoly, differs from a market monopoly, government monopoly, state monopoly or government-sponsored cartels. Unlike a general monopoly with unlimited life span, a patent may easily become outdated before even making the owner any profit. This may be due to the pace of the technological development. It may be due to the official granted time limit. But to ensure that an idea can spread its benefits to others, governments have instituted systems that have created what we now know as Patents. Which are definitely not evil. Just misunderstood.

Addendum:

Profit Maximization for a Monopoly – The Math

Any supplier must be aware of two things: Marginal cost (MC), which signifies the increase increment in total cost by producing one more unit; and marginal revenue (MR), the incremental increase in total revenue by producing and selling one more unit.

A rational supplier therefore attempts to maximize its profits by producing at the point where its marginal cost is equal to its marginal revenue (MC = MR). A monopolist is no exception.

There is a single seller in a monopoly. A monopolist can affect the price and quantity of goods to maximize its profit unlike a price taker whose marginal revenue (MRm) is given by the competitive market price (see graph 1).

Graph 1: monopoly market

7

In a market monopoly, though, the scenario is a lower quantity (Qm) of goods sold at a higher price (Pm). The slope of a monopolist's marginal revenue curve (MR) is twice the slope of the market demand curve, compared to the competitive market situation (quantity Qc at price Pc). Consumers have to pay more for the same good, and there are less available. Under this market structure, a monopolistic producer therefore gains profits that a competitive producer could not.

In economics, the total revenue and the total cost of a monopoly are expressed by functions TR(Q)and TC(Q), respectively. π(Q) represents the profit level of a monopoly producer when the production quantity reaches Q. The profit maximization of a monopoly can be shown as follows.

--------------eq. 1

The necessary (but not sufficient) condition for the profit maximization of a monopoly is:

-----------eq. 2

Furthermore the production quantity of a monopoly for profit maximization is greater than zero: > 0

and are the marginal revenue marginal cost of a monopoly respectively.


Read more...



By Werner Chiu, NAIP Patent Research & Jeffrey Chang, NAIP Editorial

Since ECFA and the cross-strait IPR agreement were signed in September, many have wondered when the goals and frameworks established would become reality. But since many political, administrative and even logistical issues had yet to discussed, many were surprised when only two short months later on 11 November 2010, when China's State Intellectual Property Office of China (SIPO) and Taiwan's Intellectual Property Office (TIPO) announced the implementation of mutual priority rights recognition for patents and trademarks.


The announcement formally went into effect on 22 November 2010 and applicants may now file invention, utility model or design patents and trademarks at SIPO, claiming priority from a TIPO application, and vice versa. Priority can be claimed from applications filed on or after September 12th, the date the IPR agreement was signed.

Previous Regulations
Prior to the announcement, neither TIPO nor SIPO accepted applications claiming priority from the other office. TIPO regulations were:

If the applicant is a national of the People's Republic of China, no matter which country the claimed application is filed in, priority claims not be processed.

If the claimed application is an application at SIPO, no matter the nationality of the application, priority claims will not be processed. The only exception would be if the application is a PCT application that originated from China.

These two regulations have now been cancelled.

SIPO's regulations were similar. If a claimed application was a TIPO application, no matter the nationality of the applicant, the priority claim would be rejected. The regulation was amended on 19 November 2010 to allow Taiwan applications, albeit with limitations in application procedure and format.

Dates & Time Limits
Applications filed at TIPO and SIPO on or after 22 November 2010 are eligible to claim priority on applications filed on or after 12 September 2010.

Time limits for priority claims are the same as those set in the Paris Convention: twelve months for patents and utility models, and six months for industrial designs and trademarks.

Deadlines to submit relevant documents (i.e. copies of application): 3 months for SIPO applications; 4 months for TIPO

Fees
Priority Claim Fee: SIPO – 80RMB fee. Failure to submit the complete amount will be construed as no claim

TIPO – No additional fee

Special Regulations
In addition to some procedural and regulatory differences, due to the complex political situation, SIPO has specifically introduced rules with regards to applications.

Assignment of Priority Rights
SIPO – A single or multiple priority claims can be relinquished. However, all applicants must consent via a signed or stamped statement.

Restoration of Lost Priority Claims
SIPO – Lost priority claims may be recovered if: 1) Loss was due to failure to submit requested materials within specified time limit. 2) At least one item is filled correctly in the declaration claiming priority, however a copy of the TIPO application, evidence of transfer of priority claims rights or relevant statement have not been provided within the prescribed time limit. 3) At least one item is filled correctly in the declaration claiming priority, however, the fee was not paid or not paid in full within the prescribed time limit. 4) A divisional application's original application has claimed priority of a TIPO application.

Conflicting Phrases/Words
SIPO - If any phrases, words deemed contrary to any laws or regulations (i.e. Republic of China, the Country of Taiwan, etc….) appear in the application, SIPO will request the applicant make amendments. If satisfactory amendments are not made within 2 months, the application will be rejected! If the phrases are deemed not relevant to the technical aspects of the application, SIPO may delete words of phrases of its own accord and is not required to notify the applicant.

Non-disclosure of Address
SIPO - An applicant may choose to not publicly disclose his address and instead list "China, Taiwan".

Benefits & Conclusion
Implementation of mutual priority rights now provides applicants with more time and leeway in deciding when to file and can reduce risk of rejection. Previously, when filing for applications at SIPO and TIPO, an applicant would have to apply to both offices simultaneously to ensure an application would not be rejected due to prior art claims. However this involved the risk that the applicant would be in contravention of China Patent Law Article 20 regarding confidentiality examinations. These issues existed in addition to increased costs.

After implementation, applicants can now first file in China and request a confidentiality examination, and then after approval of confidentiality examination, file in Taiwan claiming priority of the SIPO application.


Read more...

 
Back to Top